Module 2 case-informed consent and medical malpractice: torts and
NOTE: We do not resell pre-written papers. Upon ordering a paper, we custom-write an original paper exclusively for you. Please proceed and order an original paper to enjoy top grades.
Order a Similar Paper
Order a Different Paper
INFORMED CONSENT AND MEDICAL MALPRACTICE: TORTS AND NEGLIGENCE
© 2013 Sohn, publisher and licensee Dove Medical Press Ltd. This is an Open Access article
which permits unrestricted noncommercial use, provided the original work is properly cited.
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6 49–56
International Journal of General Medicine
Negligence, genuine error, and litigation
David H Sohn
Department of Orthopedic Surgery,
University of Toledo Medical Center,
Toledo, OH, USA
Correspondence: David Sohn
Division of Sports Medicine,
Department of Orthopedic Surgery,
University of Toledo Medical Center,
3000 Arlington Avenue, Toledo,
OH, 43614, USA
Tel +1 419 383 4000
Email [email protected]
Abstract: Not all medical injuries are the result of negligence. In fact, most medical injuries
are the result either of the inherent risk in the practice of medicine, or due to system errors,
which cannot be prevented simply through fear of disciplinary action. This paper will discuss the
differences between adverse events, negligence, and system errors; the current medical malpractice
tort system in the United States; and review current and future solutions, including medical
malpractice reform, alternative dispute resolution, health courts, and no-fault compensation
systems. The current political environment favors investigation of non-cap tort reform remedies;
investment into more rational oversight systems, such as health courts or no-fault systems may
reap both quantitative and qualitative benefits for a less costly and safer health system.
Keywords: medical malpractice, tort reform, no fault compensation, alternative dispute
resolution, system errors
Introduction
Everyone wants a safer medical system. Each year, thousands of medical errors are
made, resulting in injuries to patients who may deserve compensation.1 The chal-
lenge, however, is to design a system that compensates injury, correctly identifies
medical error, and learns from adverse events to build systems that eliminate errors.
In this paper, the author will (1) discuss the differences between adverse events,
negligence, and system errors; (2) discuss the current medical malpractice tort
system; and (3) review current and future solutions, including medical malpractice
reform, alternative dispute resolution (ADR), health courts, and no-fault compensa-
tion systems.
Adverse events, negligence, and system errors
Adverse events vs negligence
It is important to understand one fundamental concept – there is a difference between
adverse events and negligence. An adverse event is an injury occurring during the course
of medical management.1 For example, Patient A has pneumonia and is prescribed
Antibiotic X. The patient develops an unforeseeable allergic reaction to Antibiotic X,
causing short-term kidney failure and hospitalization. This kidney injury is an adverse
advent. This is not, however, negligence. Negligence is the failure to provide a standard
level of care or, in other words, the delivery of substandard care. In the above scenario,
it would have been negligence if the physician had neglected to check the chart, which
stated that Patient A was allergic to Antibiotic X.
Dovepress
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
49
R E v I E w
open access to scientific and medical research
Open Access Full Text Article
http://dx.doi.org/10.2147/IJGM.S24256
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
Many adverse events occur in the practice of medicine, but
relatively few are due to negligence. For example, a Harvard
Public Health Study estimated that only 27% of adverse events
were due to negligence.1 Medicine is not an exact science,
and complications are an inherent feature of any procedure
or medical intervention. For example, surgical procedures
generally carry a 3%–4% risk of infection. Sterile techniques,
preoperative cleansing, and prophylactic antibiotics are all
used in an attempt to minimize infection. Nonetheless, even
in the most capable hands and under the best of circumstances,
infection can occur. This would be an adverse event, but not
one due to a medical error. It would instead be a risk inherent
in the practice of medicine. Similarly, pneumonia may result in
a patient’s death despite him receiving the proper antibiotics,
blood clots may develop despite administration of proper
anticoagulation agents, and nerve injuries may result despite
properly performed procedures.
It is important to differentiate between adverse events
and medical errors, because punishing adverse events per se
would have a chilling effect on treating complex conditions
or performing difficult procedures,2–4 such as liver transplants
or neurosurgery. It would also discourage care of high-risk
patients with multiple comorbidities. An ideal oversight
system would, therefore, not punish adverse events, but rather
identify and target medical errors.
System errors versus negligence
Another important concept to understand is the difference
between negligence and system error. Negligence, as
discussed above, is failure to meet a standard level of care.
It is an incorrect decision. For example, it is considered
negligent if the standard of care for kidney failure is dialysis,
and this is not ordered. A system error, on the other hand,
is an occasional, simple human error. Deterrents cannot
reduce these errors, because they are made unintentionally.
From time to time, humans unwittingly make errors, such
as mistaking salt for sugar when baking, mistaking an
oxygen tank for a nitrogen tank during airplane maintenance,
or mistaking “1.5 mg” for “15 mg” or “15 µg” when
administering medication. This is not a decisional error, and
so is not negligence. It is considered a system error because
good organizations recognize the human error component
and safeguard against it. Health care providers misread
handwriting occasionally because they are human; however,
a good system could reduce system errors by instituting
computerized medication orders. Another example of
a system safeguard is the use of ID bracelets to prevent
confusion between patients with similar names.
According to a landmark 1999 Institute of Medicine
paper, To Err is Human, most medical errors are the result of
unavoidable human error, which can only be reduced through
system changes.5 Punishment for errors will not reduce future
errors, to ensure a safer system. It might, however, incentivize
workers to hide rather than report these errors. An analogy
is made to the airline industry; the operation of a health care
system is similar to running an airport. In both cases, many
people work together toward a common goal, and the best
systems are those that acknowledge that, due to the human
element, there will be occasional errors. Accordingly, the
best systems will implement checks and rechecks in order
to catch and contain these errors. For example, even if they
are diligent, airline workers might occasionally mistake an
oxygen tank for a nitrogen tank. It is not effective to punish
workers for making these errors, as they are not the result of
laziness or negligence, but are simply mistakes that people
may make. A better solution would be to use different
couplers for the two gases, so that a nitrogen tank could not be
hooked up in place of an oxygen tank. The safest systems are
those that acknowledge human error and build in safeguards
on a systemic level.
Negligence is actually rarely present in most alleged
cases of medical malpractice.6 In one study in New York,
adverse events were reported in 3.7% of all hospitalizations.
In over 70% of these cases,1 however, no negligence was
present. In another closed claim study performed at Harvard,
only 15% of medical malpractice cases actually contained
negligence.6 And in a 2005 Congressional Report, over
80% of malpractice cases reviewed actually contained no
negligence.8 One explanation for this is that health care
providers, from medical assistants to nurses to physicians,
tend to be highly motivated individuals.5 Rather than being
motivated by money, most health care practitioners tend to
be motivated by professional or moral ideals to deliver high
quality care and to “do no harm.” As such, negligence is not
usually at the heart of most medical errors.
It is important to differentiate between system errors and
negligence errors to identify those errors that can be deterred
through the legal system (negligence) and those errors that
can be reduced only with system safeguards (system errors).
A rational oversight system will devote more energy towards
preventing the more commonly made errors.
The current medical malpractice
tort system
Currently, in the United States, medical errors are prosecuted
under the tort system. The tort system seeks to deter
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
50
Sohn
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
negligence by monetarily punishing negligent providers
and compensating the injured parties with those monies.
According to Prosser and Keeton on Torts the goals of the
litigation system are to (1) compensate plaintiffs injured
by negligence; (2) discourage the practice of negligence;
and (3) exact corrective justice.9 A classic application of
the tort system is deterrence of known product dangers by
corporations. For example, if ABC Motor Company has
knowledge that a gas tank is positioned in a precarious
location, and yet chooses to continue production of this
vehicle, injured parties will likely sue ABC Motor Company
for their negligent practice. If a verdict is issued in favor of
the plaintiffs, the goals of tort will be served. The plaintiffs
will be compensated for their injuries, ABC will be deterred
from similar future negligent behavior, and justice will be
served, at least monetarily.
Some important limitations must be understood here.
First, the litigation system can only deter negligence and
compensate patients for injuries attributable to negligence.
This means that the majority of patients experiencing adverse
events will have no recourse through the litigation system.
Consider that only 27% of adverse events occur through
medical error, and that only a fraction of those medical errors
are attributable to negligence, and it is quickly apparent that
very few patients who experience adverse events will be
entitled to compensation.1 This, however, does not prevent
them from suing. Many patients sue when there is injury,
failing to understand the fundamental differences between
an adverse event and a medical error, or the difference
between system errors and true negligence. The result is an
overwhelming amount of time and money spent on fruitless
litigation that serves neither to compensate the injured
patient nor to improve the health care system. Over 60%
of all filed lawsuits in medical malpractice cases end up
summarily dismissed as having no grounds to even have
been filed in the first place.4 And, according to a claim trend
analysis from malpractice insurers, less than 1% of all filed
medical malpractice claims actually end up in a verdict for the
plaintiff.10 Even in these cases, most of the award is actually
consumed by the attorney and administrative costs.7,11 So of
the $76 to $126 billion spent each year in the United States
on medical malpractice litigation,12 very little actually ends
up truly compensating the patient. In other words, litigation
is expensive and inefficient.
Second, the medical field is different from the business
world. Most business decisions are driven by a cost-benefit
analysis. Without the threat of lawsuits, it is possible that
a cost-benef it analysis would favor the introduction of
marketable yet unsafe products. The tort system in such
situations helps create a safer society by increasing the
“cost” side of the analysis, and discouraging the production
of unsafe products. Health care providers, however, are not
trained to engage in cost-benefit analysis. Rather, physicians
are driven by professional ethics to first “do no harm” and
second to heal the patient. According to the 1999 Institute
of Medicine report, To Err is Human, physicians as a group
are already ethically motivated to avoid negligent behavior,
and the threat of litigation does not add to this motivation.5
Instead, litigation has a negative effect on physician behavior.
On a personal level, it creates an environment of fear and
anxiety, disrupting the physician–patient relationship and
causing physicians to fear patients as potential litigants.
On a societal level, litigation causes physicians to practice
defensive behaviors and avoid offering high-risk services,
such as obstetrics or neurosurgery. Both situations are
undesirable.
A more rational system would focus more on the goals of
compensation and improvement, rather than on punishment
for those who err. Reform efforts have been largely focused
on trying to make the medical malpractice system more
efficient. The main goal over the past 30 years has been to
eliminate frivolous lawsuits, either by reducing the incentive
to sue or by making it less likely for an unfounded suit to
prevail.
Recent reform efforts
Caps on noneconomic damages
The first generation of tort reform efforts began in the
mid-1970s, with the placement of caps on noneconomic
damages in medical malpractice cases. Caps on noneconomic
damages are monetary limits on the amount of money that
can be awarded by a jury for injuries that are not economic
in nature. Economic damages are damages that are readily
calculated, such as medical expenses or lost wages. For
example, if a patient whose salary is $50,000 per year loses
three working years to injury, the lost wages are $150,000.
This is an economic injury, and there is no limit or cap on this
type of economic damage. Noneconomic damages are much
more difficult to calculate, and therefore, more contentious
in court. It is difficult, for example, to place a dollar value on
“pain and suffering” or “loss of consortium” with a spouse.
From a trial lawyer’s perspective, much of the value of a
case comes from the noneconomic damages. There are two
reasons for this. First, lawyers often work on billable hours.
A trial lasting three years, therefore, will generate more fees
than a trial lasting only one year. Gray or nebulous items are
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
51
Negligence, genuine error, and litigation
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
often fought over for long periods during trial, so difficult
terms, such as “pain and suffering,” naturally extend the
life of a trial. Indeed, a RAND corporation analysis of cases
before and after implementation of caps on noneconomic
damages shows that trial times were reduced from three
years to one year after implementation of caps in California.13
In other words, noneconomic damages generate increased
attorney fees. Second, the potential value of the case is greater
with noneconomic damages. When a lawyer assesses a case,
the potential value of the jury verdict is calculable before the
decision to pursue litigation. An infected total knee case might
be thought of in terms of medical expenses for treatment of
the infection ($10,000), as well as the months of lost wages
while the patient is recovering from the infection ($40,000).
The economic damages in this case would be $50,000. The
noneconomic damages, however, are unknown, and could
be argued to an unlimited level. A lawyer might demand, for
example, $1 million for the pain and suffering of having to
undergo further treatment, or not being able to consort with
a spouse during the second recovery period. Suddenly, the
value of each and every adverse event, whether with merit or
not, is potentially high enough to seek litigation.
Caps on noneconomic damages originated in 1975, when
the State of California was undergoing a medical malpractice
crisis. A boom in the value of jury verdicts in medical
malpractice fueled a spate of litigation against doctors for
adverse events. This, in turn, raised malpractice insurance
premiums. In some cases, physicians could no longer afford
malpractice insurance, and closed their practices. In other
cases, insurers themselves decided that physicians were
too risky to insure, and terminated coverage. The end result
was the loss of thousands of physicians from the health care
workforce, which threatened California citizens’ access to
care. An emergency session of the California legislature
convened to address the problem, resulting in the passing of
the Medical Injury Compensation Reform Act (MICRA). This
law instituted a cap of $250,000 on noneconomic damages
in medical malpractice cases. The results were dramatic.
Increases in malpractice premiums slowed to one-fourth of
that of the rest of the nation. Trials were settled in one-third
of the time, which ironically led to more money for the
plaintiffs, as billable hours for attorneys sharply decreased.13
And, most interestingly, physicians actually ordered fewer
tests and procedures. Overall medical expenditure decreased
between 5% and 9%.14 According to Stanford economists,
implementation of caps on a national level would result in
savings on such defensive medicine by $83 to $151 billion
per year.14
Caps, however, are not a complete solution. The central
flaw of the litigation system is that it can only deter negligence.
Since the overwhelming majority of medical injuries are not
based in negligence, the impact of litigation reducing adverse
events is necessarily limited. Caps on noneconomic damages
may limit some of the inefficiency and waste of the litigation
system, but they are still based on litigation. Similarly, caps
do not make a safer system, just a less expensive one. Second,
the widespread implementation of caps are likely not feasible
politically. Caps on noneconomic damages are vigorously
opposed by trial lawyer political action committees, which
have given over $30 million to politicians to oppose caps
on a national level. While caps have been passed in places
at a state level, such as in California, Texas, and Ohio, on a
federal level, they have been consistently blocked.15 In 2003,
a national cap on noneconomic damages bill was supported
by a Republican-controlled House of Representatives and
a Republican President, but was thwarted by a unanimous
block of Democratic Senators. More recently, the Patient
Protection and Affordable Care Act (PPACA), despite
recommendations from the Congressional Budget Office16
and a President Obama-appointed health care committee17 to
include caps, was not. In fact, an earlier version of PPACA
actually contained a protection clause for attorney fees. This
has left many observers feeling that while effective, caps may
not be a politically feasible means of effecting widespread
tort reform.
Alternative dispute resolution
The second generation of tort reform involves ADR, which
refers to any of a number of dispute resolution techniques that
help plaintiffs and defendants resolve conflicts outside of the
courtroom. One advantage of ADR is that it is better suited
to adverse events than is the tort system. Litigation can only
compensate patients who are harmed by negligence. ADR
can potentially reach all patients who experience adverse
events, whether due to negligence or not. For example, many
hospitals have embraced “early apology” programs, where
physicians and hospital administrators reach out to the injured
patient and express sympathy about the adverse event. This
protects the natural physician–patient relationship as well as
encourages dialogue. Perhaps the adverse event was simply
a known complication, which may be relayed to the patient
who can then save time and focus their efforts on healing
rather than pursuing litigation. Perhaps the adverse event
was the fault of the physician; in such cases, both parties
can agree early on that the physician was at fault and use
time and money that would have otherwise been spent on
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
52
Sohn
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
contentious litigation (most of which would go to attorneys)
and divert the money to the plaintiff directly. Or perhaps the
adverse event was the result of unavoidable human error,
and investment in system safeguards needs to be made to
avoid future events.
The most popular ADR techniques are mediation and
arbitration, which differ in both their binding nature and
their formality. Mediation is simply negotiation that is
aided by an impartial mediator. It is non-binding, meaning
that if a settlement cannot be reached, the plaintiff may
pursue his claim in court. Arbitration is more involved. It is
more court-like, with an arbiter hearing both sides much like
a judge would. Similarly, there are rules for how and when
to talk, and how to present evidence. Most importantly, it is
binding, meaning that the judgment of the arbiter is final and
litigation is not an option.
Mediation has had excellent success where implemented,
both in terms of cost-containment and satisfaction for both
parties. Two notable success stories include the mediation
programs at Drexel and the University of Pittsburgh.
They have reported 85% and 88% successful resolution of
conflicts without litigation, respectively. In the case of the
University of Pittsburgh, this led to an estimated savings
of $1 million in the first year of implementation alone.18
Mediation also boasts over 90% satisfaction from both
parties.19 From the plaintiff ’s perspective, mediation offers
more flexibility than litigation, which only offers money as
a remedy. For example, rather than just receiving money,
plaintiffs may wish for a scholarship to be established in their
family’s name, or would like their deceased’s story told to
incoming nurses or medical students to help prevent similar
adverse events in the future. Mediation often suits plaintiffs’
needs better, as many sue for nonmonetary reasons, such
as the desire for disclosure of information or the desire to
hear an apology or explanation of what went wrong. In one
survey of plaintiffs, money was actually tertiary to these
concerns.19 These very aspects, however, are often withheld
in a litigious environment.
Arbitration, on the other hand, is more acrimonious and
expensive, being more trial-like than mediation. Arbitration
is longer and more expensive than mediation, but much
shorter and less expensive than jury trials.18–24 Like jury
trials, they can only offer money as a form of redress,
eliminating the more creative and satisfying solutions
offered in mediation. Furthermore, arbiters are criticized
by plaintiffs and defendants alike for always seeking
compromise, rather than justice.24 For example, even in
a case where there is no negligence, arbiters tend to offer
something to the plaintiff, just for the sake of compromise.
However, arbiters do boast 100% avoidance of litigation,
making arbitration very appealing to malpractice insurers
and hospital systems, as even a successful defense can
cost close to $100,000.25 One increasingly popular form
of arbitration is the pretreatment arbitration agreement,
where patients agree to arbitration as a condition of being
seen in the f irst place. Although these have withstood
early legal challenge,26 caution is advised before engaging
in pretreatment arbitration agreements. First, it may be
awkward to discuss adversarial postures during the initial
physician–patient visit. Second, it may actually be in the
physician’s favor to preserve the right to a jury trial. The fact
that mediation is non-binding is probably more advantageous
to the physician defendant than to the plaintiff. Because the
majority of lawsuits actually do not involve negligence,
many physicians who are sued wish for the opportunity
to clear their name. Jury trials, after all, overwhelmingly
result in verdicts for the physician.25 They may be forced,
however, by their insurance carrier to accept a settlement,
which may be less expensive and less risky than a jury trial.
This not only may be offending to an innocent physician,
but may have real repercussions, as all settlements are
mandatorily reported to the National Practitioner Data Bank
(NPDB). This affects future medical malpractice rates and
the ability to obtain practicing privileges in other states or
hospitals.
Another advantage of ADR is that, unlike caps on
noneconomic damages, it is politically feasible. Neither trial
lawyers nor politicians oppose ADR. In fact, PPACA, while
not containing any tort reform itself, does allocate $50 million
for research into non-cap remedies for medical malpractice
reform. This would include ADR.
The main obstacle to ADR implementation is the
mandatory reporting requirement of the NPDB. The NPDB,
as discussed above, records any settlement involving a
physician. This, however, has a chilling effect on the use of
settlements. Consider a case where a patient develops a blood
clot and dies after a total hip arthroplasty, despite proper
anticoagulant use. There is no negligence in this case, but
it is still an adverse event, and both hospital and physician
may wish for compensation for the family. To do so would be
an admission of guilt, since a settlement would be recorded
against the physician in the NPDB. Thus, the physician may
actually prefer to be sued, win the case, and have nothing
recorded against him. This, however, would cost time and
money, and result in no compensation for the patient’s family.
One possible solution to this problem would be to create an
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
53
Negligence, genuine error, and litigation
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
exception to the mandatory NPDB reporting requirement,
where reporting of non-negligent settlement agreements are
not required.
Health courts
Health courts are specialized tribunals where medical
malpractice cases would be decided by medically savvy
judges or tribunals rather than juries. They would be similar
to Workman’s Compensation courts, which take normal
injury claims out of the tort system and put them into the
administrative system. The concept of health courts has
recently been revived by the Harvard School of Public Health
as a means of deterring frivolous litigation and preventing
miscarriages of justice.27 One problem for juries is that they
can be confused by the difference between adverse events and
negligence. Part of this may be due to the scientific questions
involved in a medical case, and part of it may be due to the
tendency of a jury to be overly swayed by a patient who invites
sympathy. Consider, for example, the medical condition of
cerebral palsy. Cerebral palsy is a developmental disorder
with a varied spectrum of mental and physical impediments.
Sometimes a cerebral palsy patient is so impaired that he is
wheelchair bound, incapable of speech, and totally dependent
on others for activities of daily living. Such a condition may
be sympathy-evoking, but may not be caused by birthing
trauma. According to a joint study by the American Academy
of Pediatricians and the American College of Obstetricians
and Gynecologists, the “vast majority” of cerebral palsy
cases originate in utero, well before childbirth. One trial
lawyer in North Carolina, however, was very successful at
confusing jurors about the true underlying medical issues,
focusing their attention instead on the plight of the patients
and their burdened families, and won over 30 multimillion
dollar verdicts, including one $23 million judgment for
what is essentially a naturally occurring and unpreventable
condition.3 Health courts would likely not be swayed by such
tactics, and knowing this, even unethical trial lawyers would
likely not invest their time in such frivolous lawsuits. This
would reduce the burden of litigation on the medical system,
and perhaps (similar to caps on noneconomic damages)
reduce the amount of defensive medical expenditure.
Another advantage of health courts are that, like ADR,
they are politically feasible. Health courts have already been
specifically and publicly endorsed by both Democrats and
Republicans.28 President Obama, who resisted even his own
health care committee’s recommendation17 for caps as a
means of significant national savings, has already appropriated
$50 million for investigation into health courts.29
The main obstacle to implementation of health courts is
legal theory. Several constitutional issues have been raised
about the legitimacy of health courts30 based on constitutional
rights to jury trial and claims that creation of such courts
overreach Congressional power. These claims have not been
worked out specifically for health courts, but the recent Supreme
Court decision regarding PPACA likely extrapolates authority
for Congress to create health courts through the Commerce
Clause. And, similar to Workman’s Compensation, there likely
is enough of a public interest in swift and expert adjudication
of medical malpractice issues to remove them from jury trials.
However, these issues still have to be adjudicated.
No-fault compensation
Several countries overseas have taken the administrative
question one step further, and created no-fault compensation
schedules for medical malpractice injuries.31 New Zealand,
Sweden, and Denmark have replaced litigation altogether with
administrative compensation systems, where patients who
sustain an avoidable medical injury can apply directly, without
an attorney, for compensation. An expert medical panel
reviews the case and decides on compensation. There are two
enlightened features in these systems. First, compensation can
be given to the injured parties even without finding fault or
negligence. This immediately broadens the scope of patients
who are entitled to compensation, a fundamental improvement
over negligence. Second, information from claims is used to
analyze opportunities for system improvements. Thus, there is an
acknowledgement that most medical errors are actually system
errors, as well as the determination of mechanisms to seek
system improvements. In this way, no-fault compensation
systems are the most rational compensation systems currently
available: there is acknowledgement that most adverse events
are not the result of negligence, so compensation is not tied to
finding of fault; there is an inherent understanding that most
errors made in medicine are system errors, which allows the
oversight system to actually flow into efforts to create safer
systems; and both juries and attorneys are eliminated from
decision making, leading to more expert adjudication and more
efficient delivery of compensation to the actual plaintiffs.
Two foreseeable obstacles remain in the implementation
of no-fault compensation. First, the same legal legitimacy
objections raised against health courts would likely be raised
against no-fault compensation systems. Second, these may
prove to be politically non-feasible. If trial lawyer interests
vigorously oppose caps on damages, they would certainly
oppose removal of attorneys altogether from the medical
malpractice oversight system. Still, there may be precedents
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
54
Sohn
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
that mitigate both arguments. Several states have instituted
no-fault compensation systems in the arena of automobile
accidents, removing these from the tort system altogether.
Even if Motorist A is completely at fault for damaging
Motorist B, Motorist B may not sue for damages in some
states simply because these states wished to clear these
cases from the administrative dockets of their courtrooms.
A much stronger public interest exists in removing medical
malpractice cases from tort to no-fault compensation
schedules for plaintiffs, health care practitioners, and society
as a whole. Plaintiffs gain because a wider group of patients
can find compensation, a greater percentage of funds can go
to the actual parties, and claims are processed faster than with
litigation. Physicians gain because they are not being sued
and can focus on providing better care rather than engaging
in defensive practices. The nation gains because data can
be collected to identify system shortcomings to build safer
systems, rather than spending over $100 billion12 per year
on litigation that mostly goes to attorneys.
Summary
Only a fraction of medical injuries actually arise from
negligence. Most injuries either result from system errors, or
are inherent risks in the practice of medicine. Compensation
for such injuries, therefore, cannot rationally come from
the tort system, which compensates only for errors arising
from negligence. A more rationale form of compensation
would move away from blame-based systems, such as tort
and medical malpractice, which are costly and inefficiently
compensate patients, and would instead move toward more
compensation-based systems, such as ADR and no-fault
systems. The cur rent political environment favoring
investigation of non-cap tort reform remedies, and investment
into more rational oversight systems, such as health courts or
no-fault systems, may reap both quantitative and qualitative
benefits for less costly and safer health systems.
Disclosure
The author reports no conflict of interest in this work.
References
1. Brennan TA, Leape LL, Laird NM, et al. Incidence of adverse events
and negligence in hospitalized patients: results of the Harvard Medical
Practice Study I. 1991. Qual Saf Health Care. 2004;13:145–151;
discussion 51–52.
2. Thornton T, Saha S. The need for tort reform as part of health care reform.
J Long Term Eff Med Implants. 2008;18:321–327.
3. Edwards’ malpractice suits leave bitter taste. The Washington Times.
August 16, 2004. Available at http://www.washingtontimes.com/
news/2004/aug/16/20040816-011234-1949r/?page=all#pagebreak.
4. Weinstein SL. Medical liability reform crisis 2008. Clin Orthop Relat
Res. 2009;467:392–401.
5. Kohn LT, Corrigan JM, Donaldson MS. To Err is Human: Building a
Safer Health System. Washington, DC: Institute of Medicine; 1999.
6. Weiler PC. A measure of malpractice: medical injury, malpractice
litigation, and patient compensation. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press; 1993.
7. Localio AR, Lawthers AG, Brennan TA, et al. Relation between malpractice
claims and adverse events due to negligence. Results of the Harvard
Medical Practice Study III. N Engl J Med. 1991;325:245–251.
8. The Perverse Nature of the Medical Liability System. In: Committee JE,
editor. 2005. Available at http://www.house.gove/jec/publications/109/03-
21-21-05.pdf.
9. Keeton PWP, editor. Prosser and Keaton on Torts, 5th ed: West
Publishing, St Paul, MN, USA: 1984.
10. The Physician Insurers Association of America. Claim Trend Analysis;
2004. Rockville, MD, USA.
11. Studdert DM, Mello MM, Gawande AA, et al. Claims, errors, and
compensation payments in medical malpractice litigation. N Engl J
Med. 2006;354:2024–2033.
12. Confronting the New Health Care Crisis: Improving Health Care Quality
and Lowering Costs By Fixing Our Medical Liability System. In: Services
UDoHaH, ed. 2002. Available at aspe.hhs.gov/daltcp/reports/litrefm.pdf.
13. Pace NM, Zakaras L, Golinelli D. Capping non-economic awards in
medical malpractice trials: California jury verdicts under MICRA.
Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation; 2004.
14. Kessler D, McClellan M. Do doctors practice defensive medicine? The
Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1996;111:353–390.
15. Ballasy N. Howard Dean: Democrats left tort reform out of health
care bill because they feared ‘taking on’ trial lawyers. CNSNewscom.
August 26, 2009. Available at http://www.cnsnews.com/node/53126.
16. Congressional Budget Office: Analysis of the effects of proposals to
limit costs related to medical malpractice (Tort Reform). [webpage
on the Internet]. Available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/106xx/
doc10641/10-09-Tort_Reform.pdf.
17. National Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and Reform. [webpage
on the Internet]. Available at http://www.fiscalcommission.gov/sites/
fiscalcommission.gov/files/documents/CoChair_Draft.pdf.
18. Creo RA, Shogan JO, Turner CT. Malpractice case alternative dispute
resolution. Physician’s News Digest. Nov 2005. Available at http://www.
physiciansnews.com/2005/11/13/malpractice-case-alternative-dispute-
resolution/.
19. Szmania SJ, Johnson AM, Mulligan M. Alternative dispute resolution
in medical malpractice: A survey of emerging trends and practices.
Conflict Resolution Quarterly. 2008;26:71–96.
20. Dauer EA. Alternatives to litigation for health care conflicts and claims:
Alternative dispute resolution in medicine. Hematology/Oncology
Clinics of North America. 2002;16:1415–1431.
21. Fraser JJ Jr. American Academy of Pediatrics: Technical report:
Alternative dispute resolution in medical malpractice. Pediatrics.
2001;107:602–607.
22. Greer TE. Alternative dispute resolution in medical liability cases.
AAOS Now. Jul 2009.
23. Metzloff TB. Alternative dispute resolution strategies in medical
malpractice. Alaska Law Review. 1992;9:429–457.
24. Rosengard LA, Parker M. Medical malpractice mediation: A “healthy”
resolution for patients, doctors and insurance companies. The ADR
Advisor. Winter 2010. Available at http://www.stradley.com/newsletters.
php?action=view&id=524.
25. Hartwig R. Medical malpractice insurance jury verdict research: Insurance
information institute; 2008. Available at http://server.iii.org/yy_obj_data/
binary/729103_1_0/Medmal.pdf. Accessed March 16, 2008.
26. Webb RJ. New Jersey court green lights provider-patient arbitration
agreements. Healthcare Neutral ADR Blog. Califon, NJ: Healthcare
Neutral, LLC 2010. Available at http://www.healthcareneutraladrblog.
com/2010/08/articles/healthcare-arbitration/new-jersey-court-green-
lights-providerpatient-arbitration-agreements/.
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
55
Negligence, genuine error, and litigation
International Journal of General Medicine
Publish your work in this journal
Submit your manuscript here: http://www.dovepress.com/international-journal-of-general-medicine-journal
The International Journal of General Medicine is an international,
peer-reviewed open-access journal that focuses on general and internal
medicine, pathogenesis, epidemiology, diagnosis, monitoring and treat-
ment protocols. The journal is characterized by the rapid reporting of
reviews, original research and clinical studies across all disease areas.
A key focus is the elucidation of disease processes and management
protocols resulting in improved outcomes for the patient.The manu-
script management system is completely online and includes a very
quick and fair peer-review system. Visit http://www.dovepress.com/
testimonials.php to read real quotes from published authors.
International Journal of General Medicine 2013:6
27. Mello MM, Studdert DM, Kachalia AB, Brennan TA. “Health courts”
and accountability for patient safety. Milbank Q. 2006;84:459–492.
28. Health courts continue to gain bipartisan support from 2012 presi-
dential candidates. New York: PR Newswire 2012. Available at http://
www.prnewswire.com/news-releases/health-courts-continue-to-gain-
bipartisan-support-from-2012-presidential-candidates-144266955.
html.
29. The White House Blog. [webpage on the Internet]. March 2, 2010.
Available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/blog/2010/03/02/president-
obama-follows-thursdays-bipartisan-meeting-health-reform-0.
30. Widman A, Hochberg FA. Federal administrative health courts are
unconstitutional: a reply to Elliott, Narayan, and Nasmith. J Health
Polit Policy Law. 2008;33:799–832.
31. Mello MM, Kachalia A, Studdert DM. Administrative compensation
for medical injuries: lessons from three foreign systems. Issue Brief
(Commonw Fund). 2011;14:1–18.
submit your manuscript | www.dovepress.com
Dovepress
Dovepress
Dovepress
56
Sohn
- Publication Info 2:
- Nimber of times reviewed:
Module 2 Case- INFORMED CONSENT AND MEDICAL MALPRATICE: TORTS AND NEGLIGENCE
Required Reading
Almgren, G. M. P. (2017). Chapter 5 – Long-term care of the aged and disabled in Health care politics, policy, and services: A social justice analysis. Springer Publishing Company.
Canterbury v. Spence, 464 F. 2d 772 (1972). Retrieved from
https://openjurist.org/464/f2d/772/canterbury-v-spence
Friesen, P. (2018). Educational pelvic exams on anesthetized women: Why consent matters. Bioethics, 32(5). Retrieved from
https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/full/10.1111/bioe.12441
Harris, D. M. (2014). The law of tort liability. In Contemporary Issues in Healthcare Law & Ethics (pp. 229-256). Chicago, IL: Health Administration Press. Retrieved from the Trident Online Library.
The Joint Commission. (2016). Informed consent: More than getting a signature. Quick Safety, 21. Retrieved from:
https://www.jointcommission.org/-/media/tjc/documents/newsletters/quick_safety_issue_twenty-one_february_2016pdf.pdf?db=web&hash=89A718D65B453C68DA80D1B773BD1F12&hash=89A718D65B453C68DA80D1B773BD1F12
Showalter, J. S. (2020). Consent for treatment and withholding consent. In The Law of Healthcare Administration (9th Ed., pp. 405-439). Chicago, IL: Health Administration Press. Retrieved from the Trident Online Library.
Sohn, D. (2013). Negligence, genuine error, and litigation. International Journal of General Medicine, 6,49-56. Retrieved from the Trident University Library.
CASE ASSIGNMENT
INFORMED CONSENT AND MEDICAL MALPRATICE: TORTS AND NEGLIGENCE
Assignment Overview
Litigation against health care providers can happen due to a myriad of factors. This assignment examines malpractice and intentional torts. Review the following article and background materials.
Sohn, D. (2013). Negligence, genuine error, and litigation. International Journal of General Medicine, 6,49-56. Retrieved from the Trident University Library. Please see additional reading attachment
You are a new practice manager in a small medical practice made up of individual providers. For a monthly “lunch and learn” session, you have been asked to prepare a presentation examining the more common forms of litigation against practitioners. Prepare a PowerPoint presentation addressing the following questions. You must include thorough speaker’s notes.
Case Assignment
1. Explain the difference between negligence (malpractice) and battery (an intentional tort).
2. Identify and explain the four elements of proof required in a negligence tort case.
3. What is vicarious liability and how is it different from individual liability?
4. Explain malpractice or “tort” reform. Why is it of importance and what are some of the remedies that are considered in tort reform?
5. What are the ethical responsibilities of a medical practice in relation to negligence and battery? Be sure and include a discussion of ethical principles.
1
"Is this question part of your assignment? We can help"
ORDER NOW